The Euro: And Its Threat to the Future of Europe review – All stick and no carrot

Joseph Stiglitz believes the single currency is being held together by fear of what a break-up would bring. But, says John Bruton, he ignores the opportunities on offer

The Euro: And Its Threat to the Future of Europe
The Euro: And Its Threat to the Future of Europe
Author: Joseph E Stiglitz
ISBN-13: 978-0241258156
Publisher: Allen Lane
Guideline Price: £20

The Nobel Prize-winning author of Globalisation and Its Discontents has set his sights on the euro in his latest economic polemic.

Joseph Stiglitz sees the euro as a product of what he calls neoliberal economics, which he believes was in the intellectual ascendant in 1992, when the detailed design of the single currency was put in place.

Given that the idea of an economic and monetary union in Europe goes back to the late 1960s, and that one of the central drivers of the project was a French socialist, Jacques Delors, this claim is contestable.

The flaws in the design of the euro derive more from poorly thought out compromises between France and Germany, and from wishful thinking, than they do from ideology. Wishful thinking lay behind the decision to have a single Europe-wide money but to leave the supervision of banks, which create the money in the form of credit, to 17 national authorities. This happened because Germany wanted a German authority, not a Europe-wide one, to supervise German banks. And it was these poorly supervised German banks that led the way in the mistaken cross-border lending to Greece, Spain, Ireland and Portugal.

READ MORE

It is easy to see that mistake now, but the problem at the time was persuading Germany to give up its beloved Deutschmark at all, in favour of the euro. The mistake arose from national pride rather than from economic ideology.

Obviously, if there was to be a single currency there had to be common rules for preventing any one country issuing too much of it, and thereby creating inflation and devaluing everyone else’s money. In this case the mistake was made of assuming that the only risk of this happening was through governments borrowing and spending too much. This lay behind the 3-per-cent-of-GDP limit on government borrowing in the Maastricht Treaty.

But no similar, centrally supervised limit was placed on private-sector money creation through the banks. As we now know, it was cross-border, private-sector credit creation, through banks, that created the problems in Ireland, Spain and Portugal, whereas it was only in Greece that government borrowing was primarily to blame. Stiglitz argues that this focus on controlling government borrowing, and ignoring private-sector banking activity, arose from an ideological bias in favour of the private sector. He has a point.

He also points out that imbalances arising from trade deficits and surpluses within the euro zone were ignored in the original Maastricht rules. Before the crisis the Irish and Spanish balance-of-payments deficits, and their counterpart German balance-of- payments surplus, were signals of the same underlying problem. The excessive private-sector borrowing in Ireland and Spain was stimulated by the excess of German savings. Germans were earning more than they were spending, so they sought a return on their money by lending it to the Irish and the Spaniards. The persistence of this imbalance was a warning signal that was ignored. The new EU macroeconomic-imbalance procedure belatedly attempts to deal with this, but it remains to be seen whether it will be implemented properly.

More profoundly, Stiglitz argues that, for the euro to work well, there must be a consensus among policymakers in all euro-zone countries of what makes an economy grow. That consensus is missing. German and French economic views differ as much now as they did when the euro was launched. Germany does not believe that governments should provide fiscal stimulus when there is a downturn, whereas in France the political consensus would favour stimulus in almost all affordable circumstances.

Good advice in theory

Stiglitz, like the French, believes that reducing deficits should not be a priority when the economy is slowing. This may be good advice in theory, but there are two difficulties with it. The first is that it presupposes that governments will pay for what they spend in bad times by cutting back in good times. But that is usually politically impossible. This is a practical flaw in Keynesian economics. The second difficulty concerns a fundamental fact not mentioned once in Stigltz’s 350 pages. This is the ageing of the populations of all EU countries over the next 40 years. This reduces the ability of EU states to borrow for other things. The extra costs of pensions and healthcare for Europe’s ageing population will, if policies remain as they are, mean that the debts of EU governments will rise from about 90 per cent of GDP today to 400 per cent by 2060. That leaves little room for stimulative borrowing today.

In the 1990s it was different. Europe had a younger population, world trade was growing at twice its current annual rate, and growth-promoting options were available that do not exist now and are unlikely to exist in the near future. This limitation is ignored by Stiglitz, who blames everything on the euro.

He argues convincingly that the EU needs greater political integration if the euro is to be a success. But some of the ideas he canvasses lack political realism, such as a tax on German trade surpluses and a 15 per cent EU-wide tax on incomes above €250,000 (on top of national income taxes).

He argues that the euro is to some extent now being held together by fear. A currency break-up would be so unpredictable that no one wants to try it. But fear is not a healthy basis for European integration. Ultimately, a shared European patriotism and more mutual trust between euro-zone electorates are needed if voters are willingly to put their savings at risk to insure one another against unexpected shocks.

Understandably, as an American and an economist, Stiglitz does not address how this might be done. That is a task for Europe’s politicians, and so far they have failed to come up with many original ideas.

But if that task is successfully undertaken the economic rewards for Europe of having its own global currency, and its own system of mutual financial protection for its member states and its banks, could be very great indeed. There are opportunities here, as well as threats, but this book unfortunately looks only at the latter.

Stiglitz might also have given greater weight to the improvements that have been made in the management of the euro in the past three years, in the form of better banking supervision, new bailout funds for states and for banks, and more subtle economic rules. But this is not enough.

Some of Stiglitz’s other suggestions – a common bank deposit-insurance system, a write-off of some Greek debt and a partial sharing of unemployment insurance costs – should be acted on. They are needed to ensure that the euro is able to withstand the next economic shock and should not be postponed until after the German, or any other, general election.

John Bruton was taoiseach from 1994 until 1997 and European Union ambassador to the United States from 2004 until 2009